Ads

Tuesday, May 15, 2012

Getting Hired in the IP Field

 Regardless of how you find yourself less than gainfully employed (or about to be less than gainfully employed), it is helpful to know that all IP associates are not equal in terms of their supply / demand curves. 


It is generally assumed that all IP associates (and partners) tend to land on their feet after a major event like Dewey. This, I can say from personal experience, is not always the case. Depending on your technical background (you have a technical background, right?) the market tends to set the going rate of demand differently for different kinds of associates.


So, how does one increase their desirability in terms of greater chance of employment? Well, going to a really good law school is really helpful, but not an indication of success.  Going to a decent (not terrible) school and doing really well is probably not better than going to an excellent law school and not doing so hot, but it is a decent consolation prize. Obviously the preferred option would be to go to a good school and do really well (and date supermodels). So, taking a clutch of associates, all of whom did well in undergrad and went to an excellent law school, who gets hired first? Who is in demand?

Well, if you have been on any recruiter websites (or get the e-mails) you can quickly create a ranking based on demand. While the list moves around a bit depending on Litigation or Prosecution emphasis, the top spots of the list remain largely intact. So who is on top: 

Electrical Engineering
Computer Science
Mechanical engineering
Chemical Engineering 
Civil Engineering
Pharmaceutical / Biotech (PhD. level) 
Biology (Non- Phd.)
Trademark

The best way to get a job in the current IP landscape is to have an electrical engineering degree or a computer science degree.  The hardest way is to not have a technical degree at all. This doesn't mean that Trademark Associates do not get hired (we have hired a few recently), it just means that the supply greatly outstrips demand, and will for the foreseeable future.  



Jordan Garner, Leason Ellis, White Plains NY.

Tuesday, May 8, 2012

Market Forces












No, this post is not about the excellent Tech-futuristic thriller by Richard K. Morgan (although it is awesome and can be found here)

In light of the continuing mess at Dewey ( if you are unaware, see herehere and here) it is probably helpful to think about price discovery schemes for associate compensation in the current job market.

If you weren't aware, the job market for associates (new and old alike) is going through what economists call a "Market Clearing".  This is just fancy way of saying that the supply is currently outstripping demand, and either the supply will need to contract, or the price for the supply will have to come down.

If you have spent anytime talking to the management of larger law firms, you know that there is no such thing as a permanent decline in salary for associates. The reputation deficit that comes from such a move is considered to be far more damaging than the price savings. Now, this does not mean that it doesn't happen.  In the dark days of '08-'10, many a law firm took the "lowered tier" option of differential associate payments and tried to spin them as some sort of revolution in Associate salary / price discovery.

 However, most associates are not in a position where they are given the option of voluntary wage cuts in exchange for continued employment. The end result is that the price discovery is impossible in the legal market, and the only way to get the market clearing effect is to reduce the supply of associates, often through forced attrition.

However, there is an alternative:

The alternative would be to allow the associates who are performing at an acceptable level to continue to work at the firm, but at a greatly reduced salary.

It would be possible to retain two associates for the price of 1. Basically, offering two similarly situated associates the ability to "share" their salary and maintain employment.  For high-year associates, it is possible to still obtain a 6-figure income on that 1/2 share. This allows the human capital developed by the firm to still be utilized, and the associate to avoid the stigma of a growing employment gap on their resume.  Unfortunately, the current practice of picking one associate and dismissing the other does nothing to help discover the true price of the associate and results in a wasted investment for the firm.

Either way, the lack of utilization of human capital (in the form of associates) is something that the legal profession is going to have to come to grips with.

Jordan

Friday, May 4, 2012

Declining Prospects


 This is not really a post on anything other than the up-coming book by Michel Trotter titled "Declining Prospects".  If you have been paying attention in the legal sections of the NY Times and Wall Street Journal, you know that the once venerable white-shoe firm "Dewey & LeBoeuf" is on the verge of collapse.  One of the reasons is what I called in a previous post "The Maw".  That incessant desire to increase compensation in the face of declining client willingness and decreased economic opportunity. 
I am no Harvard trained economist / lawyer, but Michel Trotter is. Judging by his interview regarding the future of the legal profession found here, we are of the same opinion on the ills facing future. I for one am looking forward to reading his book, available "soon" from Amazon. Hopefully a lot of the senior partners in the Big Law are as well. 




~Jordan Garner  

Thursday, April 19, 2012

Some thoughts on "The Maw"

I have been away for a while, work at Leason Ellis (now, I think the biggest IP boutique firm between NYC and Boston) has kept me really busy.  However, I was once told that the most important time to get your ideas out is when things are going well.

Unfortunately, things are not going well for a lot of lawyers out there (IP specialists included). The causes for this are likely beyond my ability to describe, but a major factor is what I call "cost per lawyer per unit work". In the old days, law firms wouldn't compete with one another using cut rate pricing. The supply / demand curve of reputable attorneys wasn't tilted in favor of supply. Now, through the founding of dozens of new law schools, the supply metric has gone exponential. The rate of growth of lawyers does not match the rate of growth of law firms, or the general economy.  The end result is that you will have more lawyers looking for the same opportunities.

Clients, knowing this, use their leverage to bring down the cost of services.  Normally, this is just a feature of capitalism, and no one should be surprised.  However, in law firm models, forcing down the price does more than cut into a specific partner's profits.  It cuts into the firm profits. As firm profits begin to constrict, the "Rain Makers" start looking for another ship to sail (we can have a discussion on how Partners became "Armies of One" some other time). Once some of the big guns leave, the firm profits begin to contract severely. Associates, staff attorneys, paralegals all begins to fall to the budget ax. This collectively aggressive consumption of the internal human capital is a feature I call the "The Maw".

 The Maw can, and will (I have experienced it first hand) chew through the entire professional rank of a law firm without ever solving the fiscal difficulties of the Partnership. The preferred response once the Maw has begun to consume staff is to throw larger and larger supplicants into the abyss, in hopes of appeasing its hunger. This never works. All the major firms that threw virgin first year sacrifices into The Maw 3 years ago, are likely still throwing people into the Maw today.

The only way to satisfy the hunger of The Maw is to get ahead it.  This happens by reducing the cost per lawyer per unit work. The only way to do this is to lower the cost of the work billed to client. The only way to do that is to lower the price the firm pays to its members to do the work.  This doesn't always mean lower compensation for everyone. However, the fixed income that law firms provide to their professional class is not flexible.  Therefore, to be truly Maw resistant, compensation needs to be variable, for everyone. Associates should be able to ask for, and receive, a massive pay cut, instead of having the firm select between keeping one group of associates at full salary, and terminating another.
  

Monday, March 12, 2012

Inventor Portrait

In you are a patent attorney, then odds are you like inventors.  Dealing with with minutiae of corporate IP systems (I am looking at you, un-named multi-national corporations with your terrible in-house IP docketing software), not so much.  However, bureaucratic obstacles aside, I love working with men and women who pursue an idea and turn into into a tangible thing.

That is what makes each of the people profiled in these videos special, their willingness to pursue an idea until it was something that later generations can build-up. Being a giant, that lets us stand on your shoulders, is still vitally important to both our society and our economy. For that, we thank you.

P.S. Ralph Baer - as a man who enjoys Mass Effect 3 from his couch, I salute you.



Inventor Portrait: Ralph Baer from David Friedman on Vimeo.

Wednesday, February 15, 2012

Whitney Houston and the Morality of Copyright Term Extensions

The recent untimely death of diva and part time actress (who doesn't love "The Bodyguard"...) Whitney Houston has got me thinking about the recent extension of the Copyright act. (Recent as in 1998 -- but when you have a law that goes back to 1790, almost anything is "recent".) I think that the Act, even flawed as it was, demonstrated a triumph of Moral/Economic IP, as well as tangible evidence that Michael Eisner did not want Mickey to go off copyright on his watch.

Wow, that's random you say. Well not really. Using Michael Jackson and Whitney Houston as two recent examples, we can conclude that Copyright Terms that exist beyond the life of the artist, are in part, social insurance programs designed to care for the offspring or spouses of artists. The most recent extension of the copyright act is "Life + 70 years" for authors (or songwriters) and "120 Years after creation  / 95 Years after publication" for corporate authorship. Leaving aside the arguments about corporate authorship (which is where the "Mickey Mouse Protection Act" comes into play), lets look at the effect of the term for regular authors.

Both Whitney and Micheal had substance abuse issues. Likely, these issues killed them. Both Whitney and Micheal have children who will grow up parent-less in a world which places a significant dollar value on their talent. Their heirs (notably their minor and semi-minor children) should be allowed to collect on the remaining value of the works, that society is willing to pay. This is more true in situations where the artist has died fairly young.

It is impossible to calculate the value of having a world renowned (and rich) artist as your parent. As a society, we have made a collective decision that the works of art are still valuable to us after the untimely passing of their creator. Therefore, easily identifiable heirs should be the recipient of that residual economic value. As it stands, Whitney's heir's have copyright income till 2082. That's a long time. But, Whitney's child is 18. If her mother was a non-substance abusing hedge fund manager, it would be obvious that by the time she was 88 she would have lived a life of privilege.

 If, as some argue, copyright terms should expire upon the death of the author, they as a society, are we prepared to send Micheal Jackson's children to love on the south side of Chicago with their abusive grandfather and enabling grandmother? From a moral rights stand point, the value of Micheal and Whitney's contribution to society in terms of economic output has vastly exceed the amount they were allowed to collect from society in life.

Intellectual Property is not just something that evil record companies use to sue you.  It is a form of deferred pension to those who create lasting works. It is a source of economic security for those left behind, when troubled talent meets an untimely end. IP should extend beyond the life of the artist because....I don't know...the children are the future.


Thursday, February 9, 2012

You got a job, now what?

Even with last week's job report steady employment is still difficult to find for a lot of people. One of the demographics having a slightly easier time achieving the employment dream are those young people with hard science and engineering degrees. regardless of if you are going to work for Microsoft or some garage stat-up, you should keep in mind what is being slipped into your employment contract.

A good illustration of the pitfalls of not properly reading your employment contract can be found in Picture Patents, LLC v. Aeropostale, Inc.  (Google Scholar is a god send for cheap Attorneys who hate to use the Westlaw accounts).  While this case is not new (April 2011) it does provide 2 key point I want to make about employment contracts and keeping your rights.  


A bit of back story. Ms. Baker, a student at Columbia, got an job working for IBM. Excellent right! Well, IBM being a huge, 100-year old multinational corporation who builds Jeopardy winning supercomputers in its spare time, is not an entity to let something like an employment contract be a Staples brand boiler plate. The employment contract has all the obvious provisions about not showing up drunk and sexually-embarrassing your co-workers in the breakroom.  In addition it has this doozy of a IP assignment section. The relevant part states: 



4. I hereby assign (emphasis mine) to IBM my entire right, title and interest in any idea, invention, design of a useful article (whether the design is ornamental or otherwise), computer program and related documentation, and other work of authorship (all hereinafter called "Developments"), hereafter made or conceived solely or jointly by me, or created wholly or in part by me, whether or not such Developments are patentable, copyrightable or susceptible to other forms of protection, and [sic] the Developments: (a) relate to the actual or anticipated business or research or development of IBM or its subsidiaries, or (b) are suggested by or result from any task assigned to me or work performed by me for or on behalf of IBM or its subsidiaries....
The above provisions concerning assignment of Developments apply only while I am employed by IBM in an executive, managerial, product or technical planning, technical, research, programming or engineering capacity....

Humm... restrictive. You invent a newer, better algorithm. It belongs to IBM.  You invent a better toaster, IBM is making your toast. You invent a slightly tastier pancake (impossible you say!, pancakes are already at maximum tastiness! Bah!), IBM is slathering Aunt Jemima all over it. An important note here is "hereby assign" this means today, not some point in the future. So when you develop something in the future, it is already assigned (in a temporal paradox no doubt) to IBM.  You are binding future you to assign things, i.e. you don't get to renege later.

I am pretty sure you know what happens next. Ms. Baker comes up with an idea (not important what) that she developed with the resources of IBM, while at IBM. IBM declined to advance the project further. Ms. Baker decided to take the technology on the road, do some more developing and file some patents.  Later, she decides that a whole bunch of people are infringing said patents, and brings suit....and looses.  Why?

Cause those patents belong to IBM.  Yea, she paid all the maintenance fees, all the filing fees and all the attorney time, but BIG BLUE takes the prize. Ms. Baker failed (or Ms. Baker's attorney failed) on two accounts. One, when the IBM's employment agreement asked her to list all currently developed(ing) projects that were outside the scope of the the IP agreement she wrote "None".  While it was possible that at the time of her signing, she had zero conception of the project, it is not likely. More likely, she didn't think the idea was worth putting down on paper at the time.

What's the lesson?  Always divulge (in confidence, so as not to be considered a disclosure under sec 102 et seq. ) all of you concepts. Sure some of them might sound stupid, or half baked, but you never know when you will develop them into the next killer app, only to have Megacorp take all the cash.  This is easily done with something like a spread sheet that gives a basic description that lists the things you are working on and thinking about. The downside to this is that if you are too descriptive, you run the risk of narrowing your room to claim broader inventions.

Two, do not use your corporate resources to pursue personal inventions or discoveries. They hate that. More importantly, using their equipment lends credence to the fact that you were doing it for them, and it belongs to them (while else would a company let you do stuff, if not for their benefit).

The back-up lesson you kids who skipped to the end is to make sure you read your employment contract thoroughly. If you don't understand something, ask a lawyer. If you are working for a place that has this kind of contact, and you develop something on your off time, as your lawyer how to make sure it does not instantly get grabbed by the boss.